CRITICALLY ACCESS INTERGOVERNMENTAL RELATION AND SERVICE DELIVERY/CITIZEN IN NIGERIA
Introduction
Nigeria’s model of fiscal federalism
represents a fundamental legal and institutional framework for policy making in
the country. As in other federations, it defines the core rules for resource
allocation, distribution of responsibilities for service delivery, and
mechanisms for interaction between different tiers of government.
Nigeria’s fiscal federalism
arrangements are currently attracting increasing attention from both
policymakers and analysts. This is a reflection of the fact that longer term
perspectives of economic policy reform in the country are critically dependent
upon improvements in the organization of inter-governmental arrangements. Such
arrangements have direct implications for achieving national growth and poverty
reduction targets. Simply put, there is a major need to strengthen the
incentives of government agencies at all levels of authority to improve
cooperation in designing of their policies and delivery of services. At the
same time, capacity will have to be built to support such future
inter-governmental cooperation.
The need for stronger cooperation and
other reforms in federalism is driven by several factors such as the following:
a) According to the Nigerian
constitution, main public sector responsibilities are split across various
government levels. Thus, no sole government could deliver radical improvements
in service delivery on its own, which means that coordination and
cooperation are pre-requisites. However, the existing mechanisms and
institutions for inter-governmental policy coordination are weak and need
strengthening.
b) Significant fiscal decentralization
of the public finance system have taken place since 1999. Given the existing
resource allocation rules, such decentralization poses the risk of emphasizing
– rather than taming - fiscal inequalities across the states. But the extent
and trends in horizontal inequality remains undocumented, and no mitigation
mechanism has been proposed as yet.
c) Reforms undertaken in Nigeria since
2003 appear to have been more profound at the federal level than in the states.
The benefits of drastic improvements in macroeconomic policies and fiscal
discipline at the Federal Government of Nigeria (FGN) level are severely
constrained by lagging reforms in the states. The FGN is actively exploring
options for setting up - within its existing legal and institutional remits -
new mechanisms to encourage states to accelerate reforms and to improve
intergovernmental coordination in key service areas under joint responsibility.
d) The reform of federal arrangements is
politically sensitive. Reforms of the Federal system are likely to be gradual
and based on broad political consensus. This underlines a need for broadening a
public debate on key challenges in the existing model of fiscal federalism. The
post-2007 election period may present a window of opportunity for addressing
some of these issues, and it is important.
Conceptual Clarifications
The term intergovernmental relations over the
years has been besmeared with semantic confusion. This multiplicity of efforts at
conceptualizing intergovernmental relations has been largely responsible for
the philological entanglement IGR has found itself. As an instance of the
demonstration of this conceptual problem, some people have tended to understand
intergovernmental relations as the interactions between and among governments
(sovereign national governments). Whereas this conceptualization may not be
completely wrong, especially at the global analysis of government, but it tends
to paint a nebulous picture of the scope of our subject-matter and creates the
impression that intergovernmental relations has to do with purely international
relations matters. This may not be wrong given the fact that at the level of
intergovernmental relations, policies pertaining to a country’s national
interest and foreign relations are formulated and implemented (Abonyi, 2006).
Again, Ejimofor (1987) opined that the increasing role of the national
government in international affairs recently has tended to impact on
federal-state relations.
Dichotomy Between Intergovernmental
Relations and Federalism
The
word “federalism” comes from the Latin word foedus,
meaning “covenant.” A covenant signifies a partnership or marriage, in which
individuals or groups voluntarily consent to unite for common purposes without
giving up their fundamental rights or identities (Elazar & Kincaid, 2000).
A covenant represents a theological concept and political idea that stands in
contrast to organic governments based on a common ancestor and government based
on conquest, or what Alexander Hamilton in 1787 termed governments based on
accident or on force rather than on “reflection and choice.”
Federalism
and its related terms such as federal and federation, refer to a type of
government and governance that is established voluntarily to achieve unity
while preserving diversity by constitutionally uniting separate political
communities into a single limited, but encompassing, political community, such
as a nation-state. In this case, it is probable such union results from the
aggregation of separate, even independent, political communities into a federation
(e.g. the United States) or from the disaggregation or transformation of a
unitary state into a de jure or de facto federal arrangement (e.g.
Belgium and South Africa).
Insufficient Coordination in the Environment of Growing
Inequality
Nigeria’s constitution
provides for the participation of all three tiers of government in the delivery
of core public services, such as education and health. This makes policy
coordination an important pre-condition for effective and efficient service
delivery. Several factors can be adduced as justification for building workable
inter-governmental coordination mechanisms. As an illustration:
a. in the environment of shared
responsibility for service delivery, non-coordinated interventions of different
government levels create a risk for duplication of efforts and sub-optimal
allocation of resources.
b. when there is an agreement on common
national priorities and development objectives, such as those reflected in the
National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS), it is sensible
for all government levels to align their actions with such priorities and thus
complement each other’s efforts. This is because, as in common complex social
systems, there is significant potential for synergies between coordinated
policies and actions.
c. finally, there is a case for the
standard efficiency argument. Coordination could lead to better overall
resource utilization through economy of scale, quicker project completion, and
more efficient use of limited resources (such as specialized technical
expertise). It also helps to facilitate dissemination of best management
practices.
i.
Primary Health: Federal Government has been investing in construction of new primary
health centers (PHCs), but states do not provide adequate financing for their
operations. As a result, these facilities are heavily underutilized. At the
same time, states spend an increasingly large portion of their health budgets
on construction and operation of hospitals, which the Constitution defines as
federal responsibility.
ii.
Water: All
three government levels have been engaged in uncoordinated activity to
drill new boreholes, and this frequently resulted in duplication of efforts. At
the same time, there has not been much interest in the development of local
water systems.
iii.
Roads: The
national road network has been developed in an uncoordinated way, with
too much political influence over technical decisions on priority road
projects. Moreover, the lack of an agreed strategic vision resulted in
under-financing of maintenance of the existing roads, their over-use, and the
poor quality of roads which drive up the costs of domestic transportation.
2.
Issues of inter-government
coordination in education
Primary education represents an
important and interesting example of the status of
inter-government coordination in
Nigeria. Sectoral analysis reveals nine out of 12 key management functions in
the sector are concurrent, i.e. expected to be delivered by more than one
government level. Thus, the sector has enormous needs for effective
coordination arrangements. This challenge has been taken quite seriously by the
sector leadership. According to a recent Department for International
Development (DFID) report, based on cross-sectoral analysis, the existing
arrangements in primary education currently represent the best example of
vertical inter-government coordination (Improving Intergovernmental Collaboration…,
2005).
Still, there
is a major need for further improvement. In education, similar to other
sectors, more attention is paid to coordination of plans than to coordination
of their execution. Moreover, the coordination effort is unevenly distributed
across various management functions, with some functions being more popular
than others. As a result, on one side, there is a noticeable duplication of
efforts in some areas (school construction, school supervision) while
insufficient attention to others (pre-school education, analysis/evaluation of
sector performance).
Another
weakness of the current arrangements in education relates to lack of clarity in
the accountability framework. It is unclear which government level is
responsible for achieving key educational outcomes. There are also major
concerns about interactions between the Universal Basic Education Commission
(UBEC), a federal structure created to support primary education nationwide,
and state ministries of education. There has been a common claim that instead
of supporting state efforts to upgrade primary education, UBEC has been trying
to run the primary school network without showing much interest in building
state capacity to manage its primary education (World Bank, 2003). This
undermines longer-term sustainability of the recent reform efforts.
Moreover, there is a sign of
inadequate policy coordination even among federal entities operating in the
education sector, such as the Federal Ministry of Education on one side, and
UBEC and Education Trust Fund (ETF) on the other. An example is the latest
government strategy document in the sector, the 2007-9 Education MTSS, which
did not cover funding administered by the UBEC or ETF. These organizations
continue to claim their policy independence from the Federal Government.
Finally, an
additional area where there is clear need for strengthening inter-governmental
coordination in education relates to the framework for resource allocation in
the sector. The World Bank (2003) points to an absence of transparent rules for
resource allocation based on clear national guidelines and recommended norms of
per student spending, differentiated by type of educational facility. Lack of
such rules leads to major horizontal expenditure inequalities within the
education system, at the level of both individual schools and states. Within
the current system, there is no clear strategy to address horizontal
inequalities in education financing.
Recent Policy Developments in Nigeria
In Nigeria,
there has been a gradual building of consensus that the federal government
should start the withdrawal from the actual delivery of services and play a
more active role in setting national policy, financing of priority services and
monitoring. While there is no developed blue print to operationalize this
strategy, the government has accumulated important practical experience under
the Universal Basic Education (UBE) scheme. Further, as part of the 2007 budget
cycle, the FGN has designed a new conditional transfer scheme.
Conclusions and Recommendations
The analysis
in this paper suggests the following main directions for reforms to strengthen
inter-governmental coordination:
a) shift from joint service delivery
towards co-financing, state/local delivery, and joint monitoring,
b) more attention to equalization
dimension of federalism,
c) expansion in specific grant schemes
focused on key MDG areas,
d) strengthening accountability
arrangements for how public money is spent, especially at state level,
e) strengthening capacity of
institutions responsible for inter-governmental policy coordination with NPC
becoming a central player,
f) facilitating inter-state competition
on the basis of quality of service delivery.
Development partners could support
Nigeria’s efforts in this area by:
i.
helping
the FGN to carry out unbiased evaluation/monitoring of state performance
ii.
support
FGN efforts to accelerate capacity building in states
iii.
concentrate
donors’ support in reform-minded states, in particular states that are eager to
cooperate with the federal government in service delivery
iv.
providing
advice on the best international practice in organization of inter-governmental
fiscal relations
References
Broadway,
Robin. “Grants in a Federal Economy: A Conceptual Perspective.” In Broadway and
Shah (2007, Eds.), pp. 55-74.
Broadway,
Robin and Anwar Shah (Eds.) Intergovernmental
Fiscal Transfers.
Principles and Practice. (World
Bank. Washington, DC, 2007)
Collier,
Paul. Africa: Geography and Growth. (Oxford University. August, 2006)
Development
of a Strategic Framework for the Financing of Local Governments in Tanzania.
(Georgia State University. Andrew Young School of Policy Studies. June, 2005)
Improving
Intergovernmental Collaboration and Coordination in National Service Delivery
Process. SLGP. Consultants’ Report No. 184. Abuja. May, 2005.
McCarten,
William J. “The Challenge of Fiscal Discipline in the Indian States”. In
Jonathan A. Rodden and Gunnar S. Eskeland (Eds.) Fiscal Decentralization and
the Challenge of Hard Budget Constraints. (MIT Press, 2003) pp. 249-286
Rao, M.
Govinda. “Fiscal Decentralization in Indian Federalism”. In Ahmad, Ehtisham and
Vito Tanzi (Eds.). Managing Fiscal Decentralization. Routledge: (London and NY,
2002). pp 286-305.
Rao, M.
Govinda. 2002b. “Poverty Alleviation under Fiscal Decentralization”. In Rao, M.
Govinda. (Ed). Development, Poverty and Fiscal Policy. Decentralization of
Institutions. (Oxford University Press: New Delhi, 2002) Chapter 14, 278-298.
Sato,
Motohiro. 2007. “The Political Economy of Interregional Grants”. In Broadway
and Shah (2007, Eds.), pp. 173-202.
No comments